The effect of canadian imports on prescription drug prices in the u.s.*
The Effect of Canadian Imports on Prescription Drug Prices in the U.S.*
Warrington College of Business Administration
* This is a revised version of a paper presented at the 2006 Southern Economic Association Meetings in Charleston SC. Simon Anderson provided many valuable comments and insights during the preparation of this draft.
I thank Mark Fister for compiling the drug price table and Adam Narkiewicz and
Ed See for research assistance. I also thank the Warrington College of Business Administration for financial support of this research.
Please do not quote or cite without permission.
Abstract
Reimportation of prescription drugs by American consumers from Canada has
become a high-visibility policy issue. The large price discrepancies for some patented
drugs arise from market pricing in the U.S. and a system of administered pricing in
Canada. The model assumes that there are two classes of U.S. consumers: one group
who cannot reimport drugs at any cost, and a second group with a distribution of
reimportation costs. Under the assumption that the group who can reimport drugs has
lower willingness to pay, reimportation serves as a mechanism for price discrimination in
The results include the following: 1) a decline in the Canadian price may raise
the U.S. price; 2) a shift down in the distribution of reimportation costs may similarly
raise the U.S. price; 3) a shift down in the distribution of reimportation costs may raise
1. Introduction
American consumers, health insurers, and health policymakers have become more
vocal about their dissatisfaction with high pharmaceutical prices paid by Americans.
Many studies have established that there are large discrepancies in wholesale and retail
prices between American pharmacies and those in other wealthy countries. Table 1
illustrates differences in mail-order prices between U.S. chains and Canadian firms
marketing to U.S. consumers. These price differences are much larger for patented drugs
Because pharmaceuticals have high sunk costs for development, prices must
exceed marginal costs of production by substantial amounts if drug firms are to continue
to develop new drugs. One would certainly expect that drug firms price discriminate
across markets whenever they can, and indeed many policymakers have striven to enable
drug manufacturers to sell at low prices in poor countries without facing risks of
reimportation back to markets in wealthier countries.
The price discrepancies between the U.S. and other wealthy countries such as
Canada, France, Germany, Japan, and the U.K. cannot simply be the result of drug firms
pricing in response to cross-country differences in willingness to pay. Outside the U.S.,
national health authorities bear a large fraction of pharmaceutical expenditures on behalf
of their citizens, and they have implemented a variety of administered pricing systems.
While they work in different ways, these pricing systems severely limit the ability of drug
1 Generic drugs may be less expensive in the U.S. than in other developed countries. It should not come as a surprise that generic drugs have a larger share of the market in the U.S. than in countries with administered pricing systems. See McClellan [2003] for evidence on generic pricing and market penetration.
firms to earn large monopoly rents on new products in these countries. In contrast in the
U.S., managed care systems and pharmacy benefit managers (PBMs) may negotiate
prices for their patients, but only some of these organizations have much market power
on the buying side. (Ellison and Snyder [2010] explain that prescription volume matters
less than the ability of organizations to direct physicians to prescribe particular drugs in a
therapeutic class.) During debate on the 2003 Medicare prescription drug plan, proposals
to have Medicare negotiate drug prices on behalf of elderly consumers were defeated.
One argument in support of market pricing of drugs has been that drug firms must
cover their considerable development costs to bring new drugs to market. Mark
McClellan, when he was head of the Food and Drug Administration, observed that high
drug prices in the U.S. result in American consumers bearing most of the development
costs, even though new products benefit consumers around the world (McClellan,
[2003]). Many researchers have worried about drug firms concentrating their
development efforts on drugs that have high profit potential. Indeed, this is one
motivation for proposals to encourage development of drugs needed in the developing
world. However, the differences in disease incidence between the U.S. and much of the
rich world (especially Canada and Western Europe) are not great enough that research
could be directed specifically at the U.S. market alone.2 To some extent, the countries
with administered price systems free ride on drug research funded by American
2 What is more distinctive about the U.S. is the market environment for prescription drugs.
One reaction to the price discrepancies has been an increase in attempts to import
drugs from Canada into the U.S. Since most such drugs are manufactured in the U.S.,
this is really reimportation. Imports outside of standard manufacturer channels, in
particular to frustrate international price discrimination, are often referred to as parallel
imports.3 American pharmaceutical manufacturers have fought attempts to import from
Canada and have been supported by the U.S. FDA, which is concerned about the
feasibility of monitoring safety of parallel imports. Despite this, several state and local
governments have announced plans to import drugs from Canada for their employee
health plans. Currently, wholesale importation is effectively banned. In contrast,
individuals can import products purchased at retail in Canadian pharmacies, although
U.S. Customs has began seizing mail-order shipments. In the summer of 2006, Congress
considered legislation to legalize imports by individuals [Wall Street Journal, 24 July
The debate over allowing imports from Canada has focused on several issues: the
effect of reduced profitability on future drug development by private firms; safety issues,
and projected reactions by drug firms to exports by Canadian wholesalers. Almost taken
for granted in the discussion is that prices will fall, at least on average, in the U.S. We
explore the reactions by American manufacturers to increases in imports from Canada in
a model with distinct groups of U.S. consumers.
3 Malueg and Schwartz [1994] analyze a model with arbitrage costs and international price discrimination, but no parallel imports occur in equilibrium. Chen and Maskus [2002] and Maskus and Chen [2004] study parallel importing when foreign retailers ship the good to the domestic market. In our model, consumers bear the reimportation costs directly, which allows them to differ across consumers.
Pecorino [2002] has studied the effect of parallel imports from Canada in a model
with monopoly prices in the U.S. and prices in Canada which are determined through
Nash bargaining between the Canadian government and the manufacturers. He shows
that Canadian prices will rise if parallel importing becomes widespread. Anis and Wen
[1998] discuss the Canadian pricing regime and suggest that a bargaining approach
between manufacturers and the Canadian government does not capture the nature of
price-setting very well. It is, however, true that manufacturers have threatened to
establish quantity limits on Canadian wholesalers if exporting from Canada to the U.S.
What Pecorino and other analysts have ignored is the possibility that parallel
imports from another country may facilitate price discrimination within a single country.
Anderson and Ginsburgh [1999] develop a model of parallel trade where within-country
discrimination is impossible, but there are only limited arbitrage possibilities between
countries. We use a variant of that model to explore the effects of increases in parallel
imports of drugs. There are two groups of American consumers. One group has no
ability to engage in parallel importation; consumers with generous health insurance
coverage for prescription drugs often have little ability to go outside their health network.
Even if they find lower prices (before reimbursement) elsewhere, insurance
reimbursement is only available for purchases through specified retailers. The second
group of consumers has a distribution of willingness to pay for a prescription drug and a
distribution of costs of importation from Canada. These importation costs can be psychic
or real (or a combination). If consumers must travel to Canada to get prescriptions filled
there, distance to Canada will be an important determinant of reimportation cost. The
cost can also reflect some measure of the riskiness of buying drugs outside FDA-
approved (and FDA-monitored) channels. Because the first group of consumers have
more comprehensive health insurance, the distribution of willingness to pay has a higher
We approach these questions through two types of comparative statics exercises.
First, since the Canadian price regulation regime appears to have become more stringent
over time, we think about the effects of an exogenous change in the Canadian price.4 It is
certainly the case that greater spreads between Canadian and U.S. prices have been
observed over time and that this has led to increased interest in parallel importing. We
also examine the effect of shifts in the distribution in the cost of arbitrage (every
consumer’s parallel importing cost changes by the same multiplicative factor). The two
effects turn out to be quite similar in many, but not all, respects
The main finding is the price charged in the U.S. market (paid by all purchasers in
the first group and by those in the second group who purchase in the U.S.) will increase
in response to a decrease in the Canadian price or a decrease in the distribution of
arbitrage costs. Depending on the level of the Canadian price, the U.S. price may be
higher or lower than the U.S. monopoly price in the absence of arbitrage. We also find
that profitability may rise or fall as a result of an increase in arbitrage from either source
and there increased arbitrage may, but need not, cause the monopolist to want to charge a
4 My analysis differs from that of Anderson and Ginsburgh [1999] in that the Canadian price is not chosen by the monopolist, but rather determined administratively.
2. The simplest model
There are two types of drug consumers in the U.S. Group 1 only purchase drugs
in the U.S.—because their cost of importing drugs from Canada is prohibitively high.
One possibility is that this group consists of consumers with private health insurance that
covers prescription drugs. Their insurance plans only reimburse drug purchases through
the plan, so they have no incentive to purchase off-plan. Their demand curve is Q1 = a –
P1, where we should interpret P1 as the full price paid by the insurer and the insured for
The second group of consumers may purchase drugs in the U.S. or in Canada (or
through any other outlet, but we can think of Canada as the sole alternative). Let =
fraction of group 2 consumers who buy in the US (1- of the group 2 consumers
purchase from Canada). The U.S. demand from these consumers is Q2 = (b – P2), or
. For this simple model, assume that the two groups of
consumers are equal in size—we will relax this assumption in the more detailed model of
In principle, the division of group 2 consumers into Canada and U.S. purchasers
will depend on the U.S. price, the Canadian price, and the distribution of parallel import
costs of consumers. Holding the fraction buying in Canada fixed to determine individual
drug prices is appropriate if the decision to shop in Canada depends on prices in the
aggregate (as in an insurer’s decision to import Canadian drugs).
5 This insured group would also never purchase drugs in Canada unless the retail price in Canada were lower than the net price after reimbursement in the U.S.
First, we can find the optimal single monopoly price as a function of and show
that it has some desirable properties for our model.
Add the U.S. demand curves together to obtain:
Q a b (1 )P .
Q . Let marginal cost be constant and
equal to c. Setting MR = MC, the non-discriminating monopoly price is the solution to:
a b 1 ca b 1 c
For reference, the discriminating prices in the U.S. would be:
The quantities sold at this price to the two groups are:
Thus, a decrease in (a rise in Canadian imports) increases the monopoly price in the
U.S. if b < a (if the market segment which is sensitive to the Canadian price has the lower
willingness to pay—and thus has more elastic demand at a uniform price).
We could easily make the parallel import cost linear, with a uniform distribution
of these costs. That is, consumers would import the drug if P* > PC + t, where t is
uniformly distributed among group 2 consumers and PC is the Canadian price. If drug
producers were to take as given (even though they are monopolists in their product, the
import decision depends on the aggregate prices of a large bundle of drugs in the US and
Canada), we can derive (P*, PC, F(t)) and solve for similar comparative statics with
respect to PC and F(t). In the next section, we examine a model where each producer
takes account of the effect of its own price on the level of reimportation.
3. A more sophisticated model
Initially, we will take the Canadian price (denoted by PC) as given. Holding the
Canadian price fixed is intended to reflect the fact that drug prices in Canada are set by
an administrative procedure (Anis and Wen, 1998). As before, there are two groups of
US consumers. Group 1 has no ability to buy drugs in Canada; the consumers have a
uniform distribution of reservation prices (denoted by r) from 0 to a and there are N1 of
this type. Thus, demand from group 1 consumers equals D1 = N
There are N2 consumers in group 2, and they are defined by two characteristics:
their reservation price and their cost of importing from Canada. Let denote a
consumer’s cost of importing, where t is uniformly distributed from 0 to . The
reservation prices are distributed uniformly from 0 to b, and reservation prices are
independent of import costs. If distance from the Canadian border is the primary
influence on importation costs (as when consumers must travel to Canada for purchase),
independence of willingness to pay and importation cost seems reasonable.
Group 2 consumers purchase in the US if r P and t α(P P ) , where P
Canadian price. The parameter allows us to examine shifts in the distribution of
transport costs. Group 2 consumers buy in Canada if r PC + and t < α(P P ) . We
for purchases in Canada. See Figure 1 for a
graph of these regions in (r, ) space.
In the absence of parallel imports, the discriminating prices in the US would be:
and the nondiscriminating monopoly price is a weighted sum of these two:
Let c denote marginal cost. Then we can write profits as the sum of profits from
To find the profit-maximizing price (assuming no ability to discriminate within
the US), taking as given the Canadian price (set using a reference price system), we
a c 2P
Pc P P b P P P b P Pc
2b P P P cP P P c
N a c 2P
2bc2P P P 2 b PPc2 b PP c
b c 2P P P b P P P .
We assume throughout that parameter values are such that we are not at a corner
solution where only group 1 consumers buy in the U.S. There does not appear to be an
We can consider the comparative statics questions of what happens as the
Canadian price or the distribution of transport costs shifts.
Totally differentiating the FOC, we obtain:
0 from maximization, dP has the same sign as
b c 2P b P =
2 2b c 3P .
0 , and a decline in the Canadian price (perhaps as the
result of tougher negotiation by the Canadian single payer) will cause an increase in the
in the absence of imports, this is a higher
threshold, so that this condition may or may not hold.
, where an increase in corresponds to a decline in
transport cost for all group 2 consumers. We find that:
bc2P(P P )(b P)(P P )
2b c 3P, which always takes the opposite sign of
0 . More consumers buying in Canada (for either reason) moves
the domestic price in the same direction.
equals zero, we can solve for the equilibrium price, which is the same as in
the absence of parallel imports. Evaluating 2b c 3P at = 0, we obtain:
b c 3P 0 if 2b c 3
0 3 a b 3 b c ,
. (At , , for example, and a can be
smaller for larger values of c.) When this holds true, dP 0 at 0 , and thus dP 0
and dP 0 for higher values of .
There are a few interesting bounds on the US price to look at for particular values
of the Canadian price, PC. This will indicate some of the incentives for the producer and
help with some intuition. First, if the Canadian price equals marginal cost (an extreme
a c 2P
P cb c 2P b PP c .
(the nondiscriminatory monopoly price in the
1
P cba b PP c
b ab P
P c b c 3 a b
(the monopoly price when no US consumers buy in
0 , and the arbitrage possibilities reduce the price in the U.S. For a
Canadian price this low, the monopolist wants type 2 consumers to purchase in the U.S.
a c 2P 2
b c 2P b P P
1 a b
bc3 a b
b c 3 a b
1 a b 1 b a
Thus, if b c 3 a b ,
0 at P*, and the Canadian imports result in the
U.S. price exceeding the monopoly price in the absence of arbitrage. Since b c a b
must hold for both types to buy at the monopoly price, the full requirement is that
a b b c 3 a b . In this case, the Canadian price is high enough that losing sales
to Canada helps the monopolist price discriminate between type 1 and type 2 consumers.
4. Endogenizing the Canadian price
We have focused on the feedback effects of changes in the Canadian price on the
US market, while viewing the Canadian price as being determined in an administrative
process. Pecorino [2002] has studied a Nash bargaining process for the Canadian price
and how that changes with the development of a parallel import market. It is worth
examining how the monopolist’s Canadian price would change with the development of
parallel imports. (This analysis may be more relevant for imports from developing
countries—such as Mexico—where the monopoly price may be significantly lower than
in the US. It seems hard to explain the US-Canadian price differential by differences
between US and Canadian consumer incomes and preferences.)
(P ) P, P (P ) denote total profits in the
two markets. In the absence of parallel imports, d C 0 determines the Canadian
price. With parallel imports, the FOC changes to:
b PP c 0 and
2b P P P c P P P P c
3P 4bP P 2bP 2cP 2
3P 4bP 3P 2cP 2cP 4bP .
The term in braces can be written as: P P
Since b P c , this expression is positive for PC near c, so that parallel imports
may put upward pressure on the Canadian price. If PC =
price), this expression is positive for P
5. Effects on profits
We can also examine the effect of a change in the Canadian price or in the cost of
, we can use the envelope
b PP c
b P b PP cP P P cP P b P b P
3P 4bP 3P 2cP 2cP 4bP .
The ambiguities in this expression were discussed above.
The effect of a change in the cost of arbitrage is:
b PP P P c
P P b P b PP c .
An increase in corresponds to easier arbitrage—for the same cost difference, there will
b PP c b P b P P c .
If c = 0, the expression in braces equals 2b P P 2b P P P . This takes on its
b P P b P P P
bP P b bP P
9P 12bP 4b 3P 2b2
Hence, there is a range of values for PC and c such that
that making arbitrage easier can raise profits from US consumers.
American manufacturers have opposed allowing consumers to import patented
drugs from Canada and have threatened to impose restrictions on Canadian wholesalers
who export. If American manufacturers oppose allowing imports, presumably they do
not think that reimportation would increase their profits. In order for easier arbitrage to
raise manufacturer profits, the Canadian price needs to be sufficiently high. For low
Canadian prices, manufacturers would lose from easier arbitrage.
6. Conclusions and further work
There are a number of qualifications to these results, even in this stripped-down
model. First, unlike some other instances of parallel importing, the domestic
manufacturers of prescription drugs may have considerable opportunity to price
discriminate within the domestic market. Whether they can discriminate between the two
groups in our model (low or high reimportation costs) is less clear. The high importation
cost group includes many consumers with insurance coverage for prescription drugs. The
low-demand group may correspond to consumers with no prescription drug coverage—
they may have the least bargaining power and not be in a position to benefit from
Currently, consumers covered by the Medicare prescription drug plan cannot gain
from bargaining for favorable prices. Some insured consumers obtain prescriptions
through pharmacy benefit managers (McGahan [1994]) who do negotiate prices with
manufacturers. Many other insured consumers do not benefit from reduced wholesale
prices because of a lack of bargaining (Ellison and Snyder [2010]). If groups of insured
consumers benefit from price discrimination, our model can be thought of as describing
the residual market of consumers who do not buy at negotiated prices. If threats of
Canadian imports permit groups of insured consumers to negotiate lower prices, our
model could accommodate that by letting the sizes of the two groups buying at the
standard US price adjust as reimportation became easier.
One must consider that this does not appear to be a typical environment with price
discrimination in which a group with lower willingness to pay and more elastic demand
obtains a lower price than another group. The consumers who obtain reduced prices for
prescription drugs are those who enroll in insurance programs that can do a better job of
keeping physicians adhering to formularies. If consumers in this group could import
drugs from Canada as only individual purchasers (in contrast to through their health
plans), reimportation possibilities and the US-Canadian price differential seem unrelated
to the prices these groups can negotiate. References Anderson, S., and V. Ginsburgh, Price discrimination with costly consumer arbitrage, Review of International Economics 7: 126-139 (1999).
Anis, A., and Q. Wen, Price regulation of pharmaceuticals in Canada, Journal of Health
Chen, Y., and K. Maskus, Parallel imports in a model of vertical distribution: Theory,
evidence, and policy, Pacific Economic Review 7: 319-334 (2002)
Danzon, P., and L.-W. Chao, Cross-national price differences for pharmaceuticals: How
large, and why?, Journal of Health Economics 19: 159-195 (2000)
Ellison, S., and C. Snyder, Countervailing Power in Wholesale Pharmaceuticals, Journal of Industrial Economics 58: 32-53 (2010)
Malueg, D. and M. Schwartz, Parallel imports, demand dispersion, and international
price discrimination, Journal of International Economics 37: 167-195 (1994)
Maskus, K., and Y. Chen, Vertical price control and parallel imports: Theory and
Evidence, Review of International Economics 12: 551-570 (2004)
McClellan, M. Speech before 1st International Colloquium on Generic Medicine, U.S.
FDA, http://www.fda.gov/NewsEvents/Speeches/ucm053614.htm (2003)
McGahan, A. Focus on Pharmaceuticals: Industry Structure and Competitive
Advantage, Harvard Business Review, pp. 115-124, Nov-Dec (1994)
Pecorino, P., Should the U.S. allow prescription drug reimports from Canada?, Journal of Health Economics 21: 699-708 (2002)
Mail-Order Prices for Selected Prescription Drugs
(See endnotes for data description and sources.)
Min CDN price Max CDN price Min USA price Min USA/Max CDN Min USA/Min CDN Lipitor 10mg Lexapro 10mg Nexium 20mg Singulair 4mg Plavix 75mg Advair Diskus 100/50mcg Effexor XR 37.5mg Protonix 20mg Lotrel 5mg/20mg Allegra 60mg Diovan 40mg Wellbutrin XL 150mg Celebrex 100mg Zetia 10mg Avandia 2mg Viagra 25mg (transport no purchase t
α P − P ) r (reservation price)
COMISIÓN EUROPEA DIRECCIÓN GENERAL - EAC EDUCACIÓN Y CULTURA Cultura, Política Audiovisual y Deporte Desarrollo de la política en el ámbito cultural - Programa marco «Cultura 2000». FORMULARIO DE SOLICITUD DE SUBVENCIÓN 2000 Convocatoria de propuestas -Línea presupuestaria B3-2008 PROGRAMA-MARCO EN FAVOR DE LA CULTURA Introducción Antes de cumplimentar este formulario de