Si può desiderare di provare un trattamento naturale disfunzione erettile come un diverso per i problemi di costruzione. Al giorno d oggi ci sono diverse terapie sul mercato, ma un trattamento naturale disfunzione erettile è stato confermato qualche ora e ora di nuovo per dare risultati efficienti e permanenti. Cos è la disfunzione sessuale? L incapacità di sviluppare o sostenere una costruzione abbastanza lungo per fare l amore è chiamato disfunzione erettile, ED https://farmacia-senzaricetta.it/ o (maschio) problemi di erezione. Tutti gli uomini possono avere problemi di costruzione di volta in volta e gli scienziati considerano ED essere presenti se si verificano problemi di costruzione almeno il 25% del tempo. Alcuni fatti duri: ED Può essere dovuto a problemi emotivi. Stress, pressione, giltiness, depressione, bassa autostima e ansia prestazioni può essere la causa dei vostri problemi di costruzione. La ricerca ha confermato che il 90 per cento della disfunzione erettile è fisica in origine, non emotiva. L impotenza colpisce la maggior parte degli uomini durante la loro vita e può essere dovuto a troppo colesterolo, problemi cardiaci, diabete, ipertensione, fumo o alcol. Alcuni rimedi possono essere la ragione. Le questioni legate al movimento sono collegate. Se ti occupi dei tuoi problemi di movimento, hai piu possibilita di risolvere questo problema. Qui ci sono 5 consigli facili su come aumentare la circolazione: 1. Mangia i pasti giusti. Questo ti rendera il flusso sanguigno ovvio. Una grande parte di rimanere sani e anche mantenere il flusso sanguigno ovvio è legato al vostro piano di alimentazione quotidiana e quello che si mangia. Una buona cura per la disfunzione erettile è mangiare un piano a basso contenuto di grassi e grande alimentazione di fibre. Mangiare fibre tutti i giorni e questo viene scoperto in prodotti cerealicoli cereali integrali, frutta e verdura. Evitare il più possibile pasti pronti o pasti non sani. 2. Wonder herbal rimedi. Molti rimedi vegetali per ED eseguire bene come possono migliorare il movimento. Hanno molto meno reazioni avverse rispetto ai farmaci convenzionali e si svolgono in modo efficiente per migliorare hardons e la forza, troppo. Erbe naturali come Ginkgo Biloba sono utilizzati come una strategia per ED. Gli specialisti di erboristeria credono anche che le spezie o le erbe come noce moscata, portano al movimento intorno al corpo, tra cui il pene. 3. Vitamine naturali vitali. Gli scienziati sanitari hanno scoperto che una mancanza di supplemento è tipico tra gli uomini con ED in particolare vitamina A. Se si ha una mancanza del nutriente ossido di zinco, Questo è stato confermato per portare alla disfunzione erettile. Queste inadeguatezze derivano dal fatto che molti valori nutrizionali in quello che mangiamo piano non sono sufficienti. Aggiungere al vostro fabbisogno di nutrienti aumenterà la circolazione del sistema e migliorare questa condizione. Gli integratori alimentari sono completamente naturali, quindi non dovrete preoccuparvi dei rischi di reazioni avverse. Inoltre, queste vitamine naturali sono utili per il vostro benessere over-all. Oltre a questi vantaggi benessere, disfunzione erettile vitamine naturali e integratori costano molto meno di farmaci rimedi. 4. Esercitare. Fai una mossa e non un tablet vibrante. Camminare farà di più per migliorare e sostenere hardons di qualsiasi altra compressa chimica nel lungo periodo. Il fitness fisico manterrà bassi livelli di pressione e mantenere grandi stadi di movimento. Andando per un 20-30 minuti di movimento rapido ogni giorno, può affrontare questo problema e può sostenere la vostra libido senza l uso di qualsiasi farmaco. 5. Sottolineare. Questo è il peggior attaccante per problemi di erezione. Scopri diversi metodi per riposare. Alcuni metodi tipici per riposare includono la lettura di un libro, la meditazione, un bagno rilassante o allenamenti di respirazione. Sto solo imparando alcuni semplici allenamenti di respirazione che possono migliorare significativamente il movimento nel reparto pantaloni. Una naturale disfunzione erettile soluzioni di trattamento stanno diventando sempre più popolare con gli uomini. Questi rimedi a base di erbe sono preferiti perché non hanno reazioni avverse e sono confermati essere efficiente come il farmaco. La maggior parte degli uomini combattere parlano dei loro problemi, in particolare la disfunzione erettile come c è poca discussione sui problemi di erezione. La verita e che ED ha un impatto su piu di dieci milioni di uomini solo negli Stati Uniti. Non siete soli e l aiuto è disponibile.
Profitability.ijio.tex
Competing Models of Firm Profitability Abstract:
In this paper, I look at four models of firm profitability: two taken from Industrial
Organization, one from Finance, and one from the Economics of Exhaustible Re-
sources. Only one predicts that there will be a positive relationship between firm
profitability and the structure of the market in which the firm operates, and only
that one views high profits as an indication of monopoly power. Nevertheless, most
antitrust authorities base their policies on a belief in those relationships. Using panel
data from 14 nonferrous–metal mining and refining markets, I find strong empirical
support only for the market–structure model. Journal of Economic Literature classification numbers: D43, G13, L13, L71
Keywords: Firm profits, market structure, market share, risk premia, resource exhaustion,
1 This paper was prepared for my Presidential Address to the members of the European Asso-
ciation for Research in Industrial Economics (EARIE) at their annual meeting in Helsinki, Finlandin August of 2003. The research was supported by a grant from the Hampton Foundation at theUniversity of British Columbia. I would like to thank Simon Anderson, Stephen Martin, and HenryThille for helpful comments and Kazuko Kano for valuable research assistance. Introduction
Virtually all branches of economics embrace the notion that firms attempt to max-
imize profits. Nevertheless, although some firms are substantially more profitable
than others, most earn only a competitive rate of return. Given those facts, it is
not surprising that economists from various subdisciplines have developed models
that predict which firms will earn high rates of return and how those rates can be
sustained in a world in which profits attract entry.
In this paper, I summarize four such models: two that originate in the field of
industrial organization (IO), one that comes from financial economics, and one that
has its origins in the economics of exhaustible resources. Each singles out a different
factor as the principal determinant of profitability. In particular, the first emphasizes
the structure of the market in which the firm operates, the second points to the firm’s
share of that market, the third focuses on the firm’s risk class, and the last emphasizes
resource scarcity and intertemporal arbitrage.
The four models of firm profitability originate in traditions that view the economic
world in very different lights. Nevertheless, although some are better characterized as
searches for empirical regularities, all can be rationalized by economic theory. Only
the first, however, predicts a causal relationship between industry concentration and
firm profitability. Furthermore, only the first interprets the existence of high profits
Nevertheless, antitrust agencies in most Western countries implicitly assume that
a profits/concentration connection exists. In particular, most agencies require that
product and geographic markets be defined and indices of concentration be calculated
before any monopolization or merger case can be brought forward.2 This practice is
adhered to in spite of the fact that it is not only impossible to prove unambiguously
that a causal relationship links profits to concentration,3
attribute high profits to superior efficiency, not market power.
Given an abundance of theories and predictions, it is natural to turn to data in an
attempt to disentangle and assess predicted effects. This exercise is not new. Rather,
it is a very old tradition in IO that has fallen out of fashion.4 One reason for the fall
from fashion is that it is difficult to move beyond mere correlation to a determination
of causality. This difficulty arises because most of the variables that have been used
in empirical tests are potentially endogenous.
2 Many other sorts of antitrust cases also rely heavily on concentration indices. 3 In particular, under some assumptions, one can demonstrate that no such connection exists. 4 The empirical IO literature has moved from an examination of many markets using the same
model to an emphasis on case studies that are fine tuned to fit particular markets and are muchmore data intensive.
Rather than attempting to determine causality, I take a descriptive approach.5 In
particular, I look at equilibrium rather than causal relationships. Those relationships
are evaluated by calculating the principal components of a matrix of endogenous
variables, interpreting the components that have the highest explanatory power, and
assessing how the original variables are related to those components. In other words,
I seek to uncover the important relationships — those that explain a large fraction
of the cross–sectional and time–series variation in the data.
This technique is applied to data from nonferrous–metal mining and refining in-
dustries. Those industries produce homogeneous commodities that have well defined
product and geographic markets. In particular, fourteen commodity markets are ex-
amined in the application. The data consist of an unbalanced panel of the principal
mining and refining firms and include the production of each of those firms in each
The industries were chosen because they satisfy the assumptions that underlie
the theoretical models. In other words, the theories are examined in a context in
which the probability that they are valid is high. In particular, accurate market
definition is extremely important for assessing models of firm profitability. Indeed,
when markets are delineated too broadly or too narrowly, statistical tests are biased
against finding relationships between profits, market structure, market share, and
market risk. Fortunately, the measures of market structure and market share that
are used here are unusually accurate.
The industries were also chosen because a number of high–profile mergers be-
tween mining firms have been proposed or consummated in recent years (e.g., Al-
can/Pechiney). The arguments that favor those mergers rely on alleged efficiencies,
moderate horizontal concentration, and the inability of achieving market power when
products are homogeneous and are traded in highly liquid commodity–futures mar-
It is therefore important to assess whether market structure matters in that
The organization of the paper is as follows. The next section describes the com-
peting models. That description is followed by a discussion of the industries, the data,
the empirical model, and the results of the principal–component analysis. Finally, I
suggest how one might interpret the findings.
5 The exercise that is performed here is most closely related to the work of Schmalensee (1985). 6 The panel is unbalanced due to mergers and acquisitions. 7 For example, Allaz and Villa (1993) show that when homogenous commodities are traded
continuously, marginal–cost pricing results regardless of market structure. Models of Firm Profitability
I begin by discussing two models that have been developed by researchers in the field
of industrial organization. I then develop the principal contenders from the fields of
finance and natural–resource economics. All four models are very simple. However,
my object is to uncover robust and stable equilibrium relationships. Models from Industrial Organization
The structure–conduct–performance (SCP) paradigm that dominated IO until the
early 1980s held that market structure (the number and size distribution of firms in
an industry) determines market conduct (the way in which the firms in that industry
interact), which in turn determines firm performance (profitability). Academics from
that tradition claimed that market structure was principally influenced by technolog-
ical factors such as economies of scale and scope, and that the existence of high profit
levels in an industry was evidence that the firms in that industry possessed monopoly
Researchers in the SCP tradition, which was principally an attempt to assess em-
pirical regularities, often based their assessments on cross-sectional data for “markets”
(usually Standard Industrial Classifications or SICs).8 Typically, they regressed av-
erage profit rates on a number of market–wide variables such as indices of horizontal
concentration, measures of economies of scale and other barriers to entry, and R&D
and advertising intensities. I make no attempt to survey the results of the early stud-
ies but instead simply note that the relationship between market structure and firm
profitability was generally found to be positive but not necessarily strong.9
That literature, which is vast, came under attack in the early 1980s on both
theoretical and empirical fronts. Among other things, empiricists pointed out that all
of the variables were potentially endogenous and that the models therefore produced
correlations that could not be given a structural or causal interpretation. In addition,
broad SICs were not really markets, either because they were defined too broadly and
contained firms that operated in industries with very different structures, or because
the firms that were assigned to each SIC had substantial operations in other SICs.
Finally, the accounting data that were typically used to measure profitability were
thought to be poor proxies for economic profits.
Theorists on the other hand criticized the SCP paradigm on the grounds that it
was not derived from models of optimal decision making of economic agents. More-
8 See, e.g., Bain (1951, 1956). 9 For a summary, see Weiss (1974).
over, the game–theoretic revolution that swept the field questioned the notion that
market structure could be considered exogenous. Instead, theorists often made as-
sumptions about exogenous conduct (e.g., Cournot or Bertrand behavior) in an at-
tempt to endogenize entry and firm performance. Unfortunately, from an empiri-
cal point of view, the predictions obtained from game–theoretic models were very
sensitive to the assumptions made concerning conduct, and there were few robust
predictions from those models that could be taken to cross–sectional data.
In spite of the fact that the SCP tradition did not originate in a rigorous theory, it
is possible to build a theoretical model that yields the SCP predictions. To illustrate,
Stigler’s (1964) theory of oligopoly is based on the idea that, when firms collude either
tacitly or overtly, uncertainty inhibits detection of secret price cuts and facilitates
cartel instability. Furthermore, he showed that uncertainty in the percentage gain in
sales from undetected price cutting increases with the number of firms in the industry
and falls as the inequality of firm market shares rises.10
that, if one aggregates the variances of firms’ shares of sales, that variable is inversely
proportional to the Hirschman Herfidahl index (HHI) of industry concentration.
There were many later studies that attempted to remedy the flaws that charac-
terized the early cross–sectional models.11
πj = αHHIi + βT xj + uj,
where πj is the profit rate of firm j, HHIi is an index of concentration for the relevantmarket (i.e., firm j is in market i), and xj is a vector of other explanatory variablessuch as measures of minimum efficient scale and advertising and R&D intensities.12
Nevertheless, partially as a result of the attacks, the structure–conduct–performance
literature has virtually disappeared from mainstream IO research.13 Indeed, when I
searched EconLit for SCP, although I uncovered more than 100 entries dating from
the last 15 years, most were published in books or relatively obscure journals. Fur-
thermore, unlike the earlier studies, most applications were not based on a wide range
of SICs. Instead, they were heavily concentrated in a few sectors such as agriculture
and banking. Finally, I found that, as they became less fashionable in IO, SCP mod-
els moved to other disciplines. For example, they have been applied to the public
10 The latter effect is due to information pooling. In other words, a large firm is similar to several
small firms that share information.
11 For summaries, see Schmalensee (1989) and Scherer and Ross (1990). 12 Equation (1) is a cross-sectional equation. However, it extends easily to a panel. 13 In a history of thought piece, Blaug (2001, p.45) states that The structure–conduct–performanceparadigm of yesteryear . has since been superseded by game theory and transaction cost on the onehand and the Chicago School . on the other.
sector (e.g., to local governments) as well as to economies in transition or in the early
Many alternative explanations for the positive correlation between market struc-
ture and firm profitability have been proposed in the IO literature, and I do not
survey them all. However, one explanation – firm market share or size – has received
more attention than any of the others. I therefore elaborate on that criticism.
In the 1970s, a number of “Chicago–school”economists criticized the SCP paradigm
on the basis that its proponents had the causality backwards.14 Indeed, SCP critics
claimed that profits determine concentration rather than the other way around. Their
story runs as follows. Markets are workably competitive, but firms are not equally
productive. Efficient firms grow and capture large shares of their markets, whereas
inefficient firms shrink and eventually exit theirs. As a consequence, the industries in
which efficiency differences are greatest have the most asymmetric market structures
and the highest horizontal concentration. Moreover, since the large firms in those
industries both dominate the market and are more profitable, there is a positive cor-
relation between concentration and profitability. That correlation, however, does not
result from the exercise of market power. Quite the contrary, it is a sign that markets
Although the original Chicago criticism was not based on a rigorous theory, later
models embody the basic idea. For example, Jovanovic (1982) builds a theoretical
model of a competitive market in which firms, who differ in their productivities, enter
the market without knowing how productive they are. As they gain experience, they
learn about their costs. When expectations are revised upwards, firms grow, whereas
when the news is unfavorable, they shrink and eventually exit. The distribution of
efficiencies and the maturity of the market therefore determine its structure.
The predictions of market–share and market–power models are thus very different
from one another. At one end of the spectrum, conditional on market structure,
market share shouldn’t matter and horizontal concentration alone should determine
profitability. At the other end of the spectrum, conditional on a firm’s share of the
market, the extent of horizontal concentration in that market should have no effect
Nevertheless, one might expect to find empirical support for
both theories. Indeed, the simple Cournot model of homogenous products predicts
that a firm’s price/cost margin will be directly proportional to its market share, and
14 See, e.g., Demsetz (1973) and Peltzman (1977). 15 There is an alternative model that predicts a positive relationship between market share and
profitability. Bain (1956) argued that small firms might be less profitable because they are unableto take full advantage of economies of scale.
that an index of industry price/cost margins will be directly proportional to the HHI
In the late 1970s and early 80s, empiricists were able to obtain more disaggregate
data that enabled them to assess the relative importance of market structure and
market share.16 A typical study was based on a regression equation of the form
πji = α1HHIi + α2SHAREji + βT xji + uji,
where πji is the profit rate of firm j in market i, and SHAREji is the firm’s share ofthat market.
The results of those tests varied; some researchers found that market–structure
effects were dominant, whereas others found market–share effects to be more im-
Furthermore, although the issue of which effect dominated was hotly
debated, it was never satisfactorily resolved.18
The differences in opinion can be illustrated by the following quotes:
Profitability is positively associated with a seller’s own market share, but there is littleevidence, at least in recent richly disaggregate data, of a positive association betweenprofitability and indices of seller concentration independent of the profit — market–share correlation. (Scherer and Ross 1990, p. 446)
Estimates supporting (the correlation between market share and profitability of USfirms) may be dominated by a small number of industries with unusually strong pos-itive relations between share and profitability. (Schmalensee 1989, pp. 984-985, text
A Financial Model
Financial economists have also attempted to explain and assess firm profitability.
Like members of the Chicago school, they tend to construct models in which mar-
kets are workably competitive. Nevertheless, in their models, returns to investing in
assets such as firms vary considerably depending on the firms’ characteristics. One
characteristic that has been emphasized is systematic risk, where systematic means
16 Many tests were undertaken using the US Federal Trade Commission’s line–of–business data,
which contains statistics on firms’ operations in each of their lines of business.
17 See Schmalensee (1989) and Scherer and Ross (1990, chapter 11) for summaries of the empirical
18 Some researchers replaced firm and industry variables, such as firm market shares and industry
concentration ratios, with firm and industry fixed effects (see, e.g., Scott and Pascoe 1986). However,although one normally finds large differences across firms and markets, the use of fixed effects doesnot allow one to determine the sources of the differences.
risk that is not diversifiable. Specifically, an asset with higher systematic risk should
The simplest model that embodies that notion is the capital asset pricing model or
CAPM.19 According to the CAPM, investors will be willing to hold the jth asset only
if the expected return to holding that asset, rj, equals the risk–free rate of return,rf , plus an asset–specific risk premium. When the asset is a firm, the return toownership is the firm’s profit, πj. Furthermore, the risk premium is a linear functionof the difference between the rate of return on the market portfolio, rm, and therisk–free rate, where the market portfolio is a portfolio of all assets in the economy. πj = rf + βj(rm − rf ) + uj,
where uj is an i.i.d. random variable that captures diversifiable or unsystematic risk.
Equation (3) is clearly a regression equation. The regression coefficient can there-
fore be interpreted using the regression formula, βj = COV(rm, πj)/VAR(rm).20 Thisformula shows that the risk premium does not depend on the riskiness of the asset
per se, which is measured by VAR(πj). Instead it depends on the covariation of thereturn on asset j with the market portfolio. In other words, only systematic or un-
diversifiable risk matters. Idiosyncratic risk, uj, is irrelevant because investors caninsure against such risk by diversifying their portfolios.
The CAPM explains why highly risky assets such as gold need not command high
rates of return. Gold is a real asset whose return is not highly correlated with, for
example, the return to holding a portfolio of stocks. Indeed, when the stock market is
expected to plummet, it is not uncommon for investors to switch from financial into
real assets. Such behavior leads to low risk premia and can even cause the return to
holding real assets to be negatively correlated with rm. When this is the case, riskpremia are negative.
The CAPM predicts that a firm’s risk class, not the structure of the market within
which it operates, determines profit rates. If there is any possibility that market
structure or market share is correlated with systematic risk, it is important to use
measures of risk as conditioning variables in tests of IO models.21
interesting to assess the relationship between risk and return in its own right.
Many researchers from finance have attempted to assess the testable predictions
of the CAPM. They tend to reject the model in its simplest form but find support for
19 See Sharpe (1964) and Lintner (1965). Unlike the early IO models, the CAPM is derived from
an equilibrium model of optimal decisions taken by economic agents.
20 It is assumed that rf is not a random variable. 21 Bothwell and Keeler (1976) is perhaps the first study to include systematic risk in an SCP
modified versions that include additional explanatory factors.22 Most of the factors
that have been considered, however, are economy wide rather than market or firm
An Exhaustible–Resource Model
The firms that are used in my assessment of models of profitability are engaged in
mining and refining nonferrous metals. In other words, they operate in exhaustible–
resource markets. Natural–resource economists have also developed theories of firm
profitability.23 Under the assumption that resource deposits are homogeneous, those
theories yield a number of sharp and sometimes surprising predictions. For example,
they predict that the profit on the marginal unit should increase exponentially over
time, and that there should be no systematic relationship between market structure
It is possible to illustrate the two predictions using a simple stylized model. Sup-
pose that a firm owns a property that contains 100 gold nuggets that can be extracted
at zero marginal cost. In a world of certainty, market equilibrium via intertemporal
arbitrage requires that the owner be indifferent between extracting a nugget today
and putting the proceeds in the bank where it will earn rf , and waiting to extractthe nugget in a future period. This can only be true if the profit on that nugget (the
nugget’s price in the example) also increases at the rate of interest, rf . Specifically,
πjt = (1 + rf )πjt−1 = (1 + rf )tπj0,
where πjt is the profit on the marginal unit in mine j in period t.
To understand the second prediction, consider two possibilities: With the first
the owner of the property is a monopolist, whereas with the second, the industry
is competitive (the 100 nuggets are owned by a large number of small firms). Let
monopoly and competitive extraction be Qm and Qc, which can be plotted as functionsof time. In any equilibrium, the area under each extraction path must equal 100 (since
all nuggets must eventually be sold). This implies that the two paths must cross at
least once. Moreover, since price will adjust so that consumers are willing to purchase
the quantity that is put on the market in every period, monopoly and competitive
price paths must also cross. In particular, if the monopolist initially sets a higher
price and sells fewer units than the competitors, he will eventually set a lower price
and sell more units. Furthermore, it is possible for monopoly and competitive price
22 For a summary of more general asset–pricing models, see Brennan (1987), and for a survey of
empirical tests of more general models, see Huberman (1987).
23 In particular, see the seminal article by Hotelling (1931).
paths to coincide. For example, Stiglitz (1976) shows that, in the context of the above
simple model, when the industry price elasticity of demand is constant, the two paths
coincide. When the elasticity of demand increases (falls) over time, however, the
monopolist initially charges higher (lower) prices than the competitors.
When deposits are heterogeneous, the situation becomes more complex. In partic-
ular, it is not always the case that all ore will eventually be extracted. Nevertheless,
in periods in which there is neither rapid technical change nor large discoveries and
when exhaustion is not imminent, the profit on the marginal unit should increase at
a rate that is positive but less than the rate of interest. The lower rate of increase
depends on the extent to which current extraction affects future extraction costs (i.e.,
Furthermore, as with the homogeneous-deposit case, there
is no simple relationship between firm profitability and the structure of the market
in which the firm operates. In particular, with heterogeneous deposits, if exhaustion
is complete, monopoly and competitive price and extraction paths must cross.25
There have been many attempts to test the implications of resource scarcity for
profitability, and support for the model is limited at best. Those tests tend to be
either time–series examinations of prices and profits (e.g., Heal and Barrow 1980,
Smith 1981, and Slade 1982) or more structural dynamic models (e.g., Halvorsen and
Smith 1984, Farrow 1985, Young 1992, Slade and Thille 1997, and Ellis and Halvorsen
2002).26 The structural studies, however, require much more detailed data.
There is clearly an abundance of theories of firm profitability. The predicted
equilibrium relationships are summarized in table 1. In that table, rows are theories,
columns are variables that can be constructed from data, and entries indicate signs
of predicted correlations with firm profits. It is useful to adopt a unified empirical
framework in which to assess the summarized predictions. I now turn to such an
The Nonferrous–Metal Industries
The production of nonferrous metals consists of several phases. In simple terms, the
exploration process produces reserves of metal ore, mining extracts that ore from the
ground, smelting and refining produce metal from the extracted ore, and downstream
firms (e.g., mills) produce metal products (e.g., sheet and tube) from the output of the
refineries and smelters. With the exception of the last phase, most of the large min-
24 See Levhari and Levitan (1977). 25 Exhaustion will be complete if, for example, the demand choke price is infinite and if extraction
costs are multiplicatively separable in current extraction and remaining reserves.
26 The Slade and Thille paper combines a test of the theory of exhaustible resources with the
CAPM, whereas the Ellis and Halvorsen paper combines that theory with a test of market power.
ing companies are vertically integrated and are involved in all phases of production.
However, the exploration phase is much more fragmented than the others. Indeed,
many small firms engage only in exploration and sell the deposits that they discover
to mining companies. For this reason, in my empirical analysis I limit attention to
phases two and three — mining and refining.27
The principal nonferrous metals are aluminum, copper, gold, lead, nickel, silver,
tin, and zinc. With the exception of aluminum companies, most large mining firms
operate in several commodity markets. Multimarket production is due to two factors.
First, many ores contain more than one metal (e.g., lead and zinc), and production
must be joint. Second, the technology of mining is similar across commodities, which
means that a firm with experience with one commodity can easily transfer that ex-
There are substantial economies of scale in mining and even more in refining. As
a consequence, mining firms are included in lists of the world’s largest. However, the
markets in which they operate are also large. Indeed, nonferrous–metal markets are
worldwide. Due to their geographic size, markets for individual commodities are not
highly concentrated. Instead, they range from moderately concentrated to workably
In addition to economies of scale, entry barriers include the need to possess a
scarce resource. In particular, one cannot mine unless one owns an ore deposit.
Furthermore, it is uneconomical to enter the market if the deposit that one owns is
Technological breakthroughs revolutionized the mining industry in the late nine-
teenth and early twentieth centuries. To illustrate, the availability of cheap sources
of electricity made aluminum smelting possible, the discovery of froth flotation made
recovery of metals from sulfide ores economical, and the advent of large earth–moving
equipment made strip mining of low–grade surface deposits inexpensive. In recent
years, however, there have been few breakthroughs. Nevertheless, there are constant
small, gradual improvements in the technology of mining.
On the production side, mineral commodities are thus similar to one another in
many respects. To reiterate, i) they are homogenous commodities that are sold in
world markets, ii) their technologies exhibit economies of scale, but minimum efficient
scales are not usually large relative to market sizes, iii) they are industrial goods that
are not subject to rapid technological change, and iv) their technologies are capital
intensive with similar rates of depreciation across commodities.
On the consumption side, in contrast, the principal uses for a given commodity are
27 Henceforth, I use the word refining to denote smelting and refining and sometimes use the word
mining (e.g., mining firm) to denote mining, smelting, and refining.
quite different from those for the others. For example, the largest use of aluminum
is in the container and food–packaging sector, whereas the largest use of lead is in
storage batteries. This means that each commodity is sold in a different product
market. The combination of these factors implies that both geographic and product
markets are well defined. In particular, there are 16 world markets corresponding to
the eight commodities at two stages of production.
These industries are thus ideal for testing market–structure and market–share
models. Indeed, when products are homogeneous and markets are accurately defined,
those models are most apt to be capable of capturing cross–sectional and time–series
variation in firm profitability. Unfortunately, the industries are less well suited to
testing the relationship between risk and return. As we shall see, the problem arises
because, although the markets are highly risky, that risk is principally unsystematic.
Prices of each commodity come from the London Metal Exchange (aluminum, copper,
lead, nickel, tin, and zinc) and from COMEX (gold and silver).28
monthly averages of the daily data were used in constructing commodity-market and
The data on firms — output of each commodity, company profits, and assets at
each stage of production — were obtained from the Raw Materials Group (RMG), a
consulting firm in Sweden.29 These data are somewhat unusual. Indeed, most data–
collection agencies publish commodity statistics by geographic region, and those data
contain no information on market structure. The Raw Materials Group, in contrast,
keeps track of the activities of mining companies. In particular, it tracks mergers
and other changes in the complex linkages among mining and refining firms and is
consequently a unique source of information on who owns and controls whom.
RMG does not keep track of refining of silver and gold. This omission is perhaps
due to the fact that flows of newly refined silver and gold are small relative to the
stocks of those commodities that are in circulation. In other words, silver and gold
are not discarded but remain in use or are recycled. This lack of data reduces the
total number of markets to 14, eight mining and six refining markets.
Most of the data are annual for the 1994-1998 period. 1994 is the first year for
which profit data are available, and 1998 was the last year available at the time of
purchase of the data. Although 5 years is not long enough to estimate a dynamic
model, it is the approximate length of a business cycle.
28 COMEX is now part of NYMEX. 29 For more information on the Raw Materials Group, see their web page at www.rmg.se.
An observation is a firm, i, i = 1, . . . , Ij, at a stage of production j, j = 1, 2, in a
year t, t = ti, . . . , Ti. Although there is much overlap, the number and identities ofthe mining and the refining firms differ (thus the j subscript on I). Furthermore, due
to mergers and acquisitions, the panel is unbalanced (thus the subscript i on t).
82 mining and 54 refining companies were selected for the analysis. The selection
procedure was as follows. For each commodity, year, and phase of production, the 20
All companies that made the cut for at least one
year and commodity were initially considered. However, companies were dropped if
no profit data were available, which reduced the number of companies in each set. In
addition, observations were dropped from the sample if either profit or output data
were incomplete, which is another reason why the panel is unbalanced. The final
sample contains 320 observations on mining and 210 observations on refining firms.
A number of variables were constructed from the raw data. First consider the
profit rates. Nominal profits net of taxes are recorded in $US for each firm at each
stage of production. To make nominal profits comparable across companies, they
were normalized in two ways: they were divided by the firm’s total revenue and by
its assets (also in $US) and multiplied by 100. Real profit rates were then created by
subtracting the annual rate of inflation in OECD countries from the nominal profit
rates. The real profit rate in percentage is denoted RP ROF ITit when divided byrevenue and AP ROF ITit when divided by assets. For ease of notation, the phase ofproduction has been suppressed here and in what follows.
Four commodity–market variables were constructed. The first is the Hirschman
Herfindahl index of concentration, CHHIkt, which is the sum of the squared sharesof output of the firms that operate in commodity market k in year t, multiplied
by 10,000. The second is the four-firm concentration ratio, CCR4kt, which is thepercentage of industry output that is attributable to the four largest firms in that
industry and year. The third is the commodity beta, CBET Ak, which is calculatedas COV(rk, rm)/VAR(rm). For this calculation, rk is the rate of price appreciationfor commodity k,31
and rm is an average of the total returns (capital gains plus
dividends) to holding a number of prominent stock–market indices.32 Monthly data
for the 1990-1998 period were used in estimating the betas. The final commodity–
market variable, CCU M EXkt, measures cumulative extraction of each commodity.
30 I limit attention to large companies because, with those companies, economies of scale are apt to
be exhausted. In other words, I want to eliminate the possibility that finding a positive relationshipbetween size and profitability is due to economies of scale.
31 rk is the capital gain that is associated with holding the processed commodity. A better measure
of risk would use shadow rather than market prices (see, e.g., Slade and Thille 1997).
32 Specifically, the indices are Standard and Poors 500 (US), the Dow Jones Industrial Average
(US), FTSE 100 (UK), CAC 40 (France), Hang Seng (Hong Kong), TSE 300 (Canada), Nikkei 500(Japan), and DAX 30 (Germany). Firm variables other than profit rates are weighted averages, where the weights
are revenue or output shares. In other words, wikt (Wikt) is the fraction of firm i’srevenue (output) that comes from its operations in commodity market k in year t.
The first two firm variable are its HHI and its CR4, which are weighted averages of
The third firm variable is i’s market share, F M KT SHit, which is a weighted
average of its shares of the commodity markets in which it operates,
where SHAREikt is firm i’s share of the output of commodity market k in year t. This variable is in percentage. In addition, an alternative measure of market share,
F M AXSHit, was constructed. This measure is the largest share of any of the marketsin which a firm operates. In other words, if a firm were to produce three metals, and if
its shares of its three commodity markets were 0.5%, 10%, and 5%, the new measure
The fifth firm variable, which is a weighted average of the commodity betas, is a
proxy for firm i’s risk premium,33
Finally, an exponential trend equal to exp(0.05t) was created. A 5% annual real
rate of interest was assumed in creating that variable, which is denoted T REN Dt. This variable should be correlated with profits when deposits are homogeneous. In
addition, the variable CCU M EXkt that measures cumulative extraction for eachcommodity was weighted by the output weights, Wikt, to obtain cumulative extractionfor each firm, F CU M EXit. This variable is a better measure of depletion whendeposits are heterogeneous.
A number of comments on the data are in order. First, much has been written
about the relative merits of various measures of profitability. My preferred measure
is RP ROF IT , which is often equated with the price/cost margin in the SCP lit-
erature. The principal drawback to using that measure is related to the fact that
33 An alternative measure of the risk premium would use company profits as ri. However, there
are only five observations from which to construct that variable.
rates of depreciation and competitive rates of return differ across industries (see, e.g.,
Schmalensee 1989). Within the mining sector, however, this problem is not severe.
An advantage of normalizing by sales is that data on sales are much more reliable
than data on capital stocks. More generally, however, the use of any accounting data
has its limitations, which are no more or less troubling here than in other applications.
Profits are recorded by firm rather than by each market in which the firm operates.
This lack of detail is less troublesome than it might at first appear. Indeed, it is always
difficult to allocate joint costs. However, the problem is particularly acute in the
mining industry. To illustrate, when an ore is extracted, it can be difficult to know apriori which metals the ore will contain. Moreover, even when the metals are known,
the grades of each can usually only be determined ex post. Furthermore, when mining
firms allocate joint costs across commodities, they often assign all joint costs to the
primary or high–revenue commodity. This procedure makes economic sense since, at
the margin, capacity expansions are usually driven by a desire to produce more of
the more profitable commodity. However, for the purpose of this study, the practice
has the drawback of implying that, as the price of a metal increases, its costs can
also appear to increase, and low–value metals (byproducts) appear to be produced
at very low cost. For this reason, even if available, profits by line of business would
be unreliable. Revenues, in contrast, can be accurately constructed for each market,
and those revenues are used to form the weights that enter into the construction of
In contrast to the measure of profitability, the measures of market structure that
are used here are unusually accurate. Indeed, both product and geographic markets
are well defined, and the raw data on firm output is recorded at the appropriate
market level. The data were collected at two phases of production. Although refining
markets are clearly important, due to the prevalence of vertical integration, one might
question the relevance of mining markets. For this reason, the empirical model is
estimated for each phase of production separately.
SCP studies typically employ many other control variables. For example, it is
common to include measures of R&D and advertising intensities and dummy variables
that indicate whether the product is durable and whether it is a consumer or a
producer good. With my data, due to the similarity of the markets, there is no need
Finally, one problem with the use of a single cross section is that the relationships
of interest are apt to vary over the business cycle. Using a panel that is at least as
long as a typical business cycle, as is done here, eliminates that problem.
Table 2 gives summary statistics by phase of production for each of the four
endogenous variables that are used in the analysis. The variables have been scaled
so that they have similar means. In particular, the HHI has been divided by 100 so
that it ranges between 0 for perfect competition and 100 for monopoly, and the betas
The table shows that, at least in mining, the variation in profit rates is substan-
tially greater than the variation in the other variables. Moreover, in spite of the
fact that mining and refining are highly risky activities, the betas are small, which
is not unexpected. The table also shows that the largest firms in the sample (as
measured by FMKTSH) control just over 20% of the markets in which they operate.
Finally, markets vary between fairly competitive (the usual HHI = 180) to moderately
The Empirical Model
Much of the variation in the data is cross sectional, and differences across firms
are relatively stable. This means that one can interpret cross sectional variation in
the firm variables, RPROFIT, FHHI, FMKTSH, and FBETA, as long–run stable
differences. Unfortunately, this also means that all of those variables are potentially
endogenous. Moreover, without firm–level exogenous variables, such as firm–specific
factor prices, it is difficult to find instruments that could be used in a regression
analysis. For this reason, a descriptive approach is adopted. In particular, I use
principal components to analyze variations in the data.
Principal components transforms a set of variables, X, into a new set of variables,
Z, that are pairwise uncorrelated. Furthermore, the first of the Z variables (or
components) has the maximum possible variance, the second has the maximum among
those that are uncorrelated with the first, and so forth. If there are M variables in
the original data, x , = 1, . . . , M , and if those variables are not perfectly collinear,
it is always possible to find M linearly–independent components, z ,
that explain all of the variation in X.34
However, it is often the case that m < M
components explain a very large fraction of the variation.
The components are linear combinations of the original variables, and it is not
always possible to give each an economic interpretation. However, sometimes one
can. Whether or not one can interpret the components, it is possible to calculate
correlation coefficients between each component and each of the original variables.
One can also calculate the proportion of the variation in each x that is associated
The procedure adopted here is to consider a matrix X that consists of the four
34 For the expression “the variation in X” to make sense, the constituent vectors should be
measured in the same units. The variables in this study can be loosely interpreted as percentages.
endogenous firm variables that are shown in table 2 plus the exponential trend (M =
5). Five principal components are computed. The number m that is retained is chosen
as the smallest number of components that explains at least 95% of the variation in X.
An attempt is then made to interpret the retained components, and the correlations
between the original variables and those components are calculated. The Principal–Component Analysis
Table 3 shows the contribution of the first 3 principal components to the total vari-
ation in X, both individually and jointly, for both phases of production. One can
see that the first component accounts for more than 60% of the variation, the second
for about 10–30%, and the third for 4–7%. There is therefore very little variation
left for the last two components to explain. Moreover, given the rule for retention of
components, the first two are retained for mining and the first three are retained for
Table 4 contains correlation coefficients between each variable in X and the re-
tained components for both phases of production. The first thing to notice is that the
first component is essentially profit, RP ROF IT , the second is essentially the risk pre-
mium, F BET A, and, for refining, the third is essentially market share, F M KT SH.
Indeed, the correlation between those variables and the respective components is at
least 0.95 in all five cases. In particular, this means that RP ROF IT and F M KT SH
are orthogonal to one another in refining. In other words, in those industries there
is no systematic relationship between a firm’s market share and its profitability, and,
within a market, smaller firms are just as profitable as larger ones.
This finding is contrary to what the proponents of “market–share” models pre-
dict. In particular, even though the firms in the sample are all large, they control
between 0.1 and 21% of the markets in which they operate. Variation in F M KT SH
is therefore substantial. That variation, however, is uncorrelated with profitability.
Furthermore, this finding implies that, if there is a correlation between profitability
and market structure in those markets, it cannot be due to a failure to control for
the common causal factor, market share.
Since one can interpret the first three components as profit, systematic risk, and
market share respectively, it is possible to investigate how those variables are related
to the remaining variables. In particular, the correlations in table 4 reemphasize the
fact that a firm’s market share is not correlated with its profitability as embodied in
Table 4 shows that the market–structure variable, F HHI, is positively correlated
with all of the retained components. Moreover, those correlations are significant at
1%. The implications are that firms that operate in concentrated markets are more
profitable and command higher risk premia, and concentrated refining markets have
larger firms (in relative terms). The first of these conclusions gives support to the
traditional structure–conduct–performance paradigm. In other words, market struc-
ture matters. The third, which is more of an accounting identity, simply implies that
if some firms control large shares of a market, that market is apt to be concentrated.
The measure of systematic risk, F BET A, which is proportional to the firm’s
risk premium, is positively correlated with profits in mining but not in refining. The
results are therefore mixed, and the CAPM receives only partial support. This finding,
however, might simply be due to the fact that all of the estimated betas are small,
which means that none of the firms in the sample commands a high rate of return as
Finally, profits do not exhibit an upward trend. In fact, there appears to be a
downward trend in mining profitability. Sensitivity Analysis
The robustness of the results was assessed in a number of ways. In particular, the
calculations were redone using profit divided by assets, AP ROF IT , as an alterna-
tive measure of profitability, using the four–firm concentration ratio, F CR4, as an
alternative measure of market structure, the variable, F M AXSH, as an alternative
measure of market share, and with F CU M EX as an alternative measure of scarcity.
In addition, I created a firm–specific trend that depends on the firm’s risk premium,
F BET A. Finally, the commodity risk premium, CBET A, was allowed to vary by
year. None of the alternative specifications, however, changed the qualitative nature
For the final specification test, I performed the calculations for each year in the
data. When I did this, I found that the relationship between profits and market
structure is stronger in economic downturns. This finding might indicate that firms
in all industries do well in upturns, and in fact I find that profits are positively
related to industrial production. Firms in concentrated industries, however, might
have better methods of disciplining each other and might therefore be less likely to
suffer profit losses in periods when demand is falling. Conclusions
Four models of firm profitability were surveyed, each originating in a different tra-
dition and each focusing on a different determinant of profitability. The first, the
familiar structure–conduct–performance (SCP) model, predicts that the structure of
the market in which the firm operates will be the most important determinant of its
profits. The second predicts that firms with large market shares will be profitable and
that failure to condition on market share will bias the results of tests of SCP models.
The third singles out a firm’s risk class and predicts that firms that must bear more
systematic risk will earn higher rates of return. Finally, the fourth predicts a tempo-
ral increase in profits as the firm’s reserves are depleted and scarcity rents are earned.
Although at times mutually contradictory, the predictions from all four models can
be rationalized by rigorous theories. The question of what actually determines firm
profitability is therefore an empirical issue.
Using panel data from nonferrous mining and refining markets, I am able to assess
each prediction. I find strong support for the first (SCP) model. Indeed, firms’ profits
are positively and significantly related to the structures of their markets, and this
relationship holds in all specifications that were estimated. A firm’s market share,
in contrast, is found to be uncorrelated with its profitability. This means that, not
only is market share not an important determinant of profitability in nonferrous–
metal markets, but also that the correlation between market structure and profits
is not spurious. A firm’s risk premium, which is a measure of the systematic risk
that it must bear, is found to be positively correlated with profitability in mining
but not in refining. The latter finding, however, is perhaps due to the fact that in
the industries studied, there is not much variation in risk premia across firms and
time periods. Finally, there is no evidence of a temporal increase in profits. These
empirical regularities are summarized in the last row of table 1 under the heading of
It is perhaps worth elaborating on the second finding. It is somewhat surprising
that market share does not affect profitability in these industries. In particular, since
low-cost firms should expand more in an upturn and contract less in a downturn,
most economic models predict that size, even when not the principal determinant
of profitability, will be positively correlated with it. My counterintuitive finding can
be explained, however, if some firms are capacity constrained while others are not.
Under that hypothesis, output expansions will be undertaken by the unconstrained
firms, which need not be the low-marginal-cost firms. Furthermore, this is not just a
short–run phenomenon since, in exhaustible–resource industries, capacities are more
apt to be determined by reserves than by marginal costs.
I began by stating that competition authorities rely heavily on concentration in-
dices as tools for determining potential competitive harm. The issue of whether this
practice is justified is clearly not resolved. Most economists would agree, however,
that it does not work well when products are differentiated. For this reason, authori-
ties are starting to supplement the conventional analysis with merger simulations and
other more sophisticated evaluation methods. This practice, however, is also prob-
lematic. For example, the results of merger simulations are sensitive to the choice
of functional form for demand equations. Furthermore, the predictions that are ob-
tained depend heavily on the cross–price elasticities that are used. Unfortunately, the
magnitudes of estimated elasticities are sensitive to the choice of the outside good as
well as to the number of alternatives considered.35 When products are homogeneous,
shares may thus be as good indicators as simulations. It is therefore unlikely that the
traditional approach will be totally abandoned in the near future.
35 A general discussion of the alternatives is beyond the scope of this paper. Interested readers
References Cited
Allaz, B. and Villa, J-L. (1993) “Cournot Competition, Forward Markets, and Effi-
ciency,” Journal of Economic Theory, 59: 1-16.
Bain, J.S. (1951) “Relation of Profit Rate to Industry Concentration: American Man-
ufacturing,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 65: 293–324.
Bain, J.S. (1956) Barriers to New Competition, Harvard University Press.
Blaug, M. (2001) “Is Competition Such a Good Thing? Static Efficiency versus Dy-
namic Efficiency,” Review of Industrial Organization, 19: 37–48.
Bothwell, J.L. and Keeler, T.E. (1976) “Profits, Market Structure, and Portfolio Risk,”
in Essays in Industrial Organization in Honor of Joe S. Bain, R.T. Masson and
Brennan, M.J. (1987) “Capital Asset Pricing Model,” in The New Palgrave, Finance,
Eatwell, J., Milgate. M., and Newman, P. (eds) New York: W.W. Norton.
Cowling, K. and Waterson, M. (1976) “Price–Cost Margins and Market Structure,”
Demsetz, H. (1973) “Industry Structure, Market Rivalry, and Public Policy,” Journalof Law and Economics, 16: 1–10.
Ellis, G.M. and Halvorsen, R. (2002) “Estimation of Market Power in a Nonrenew-
able Resource Industry,” Journal of Political Economy, 110: 883–899.
Farrow, S. (1985) “Testing the Efficiency of Extraction from a Stock Resource,” Jour-nal of Political Economy, 93: 452-487.
Halvorsen, R. and Smith, (1984) “On Measuring Natural-Resource Scarcity,” Jour-nal of Political Economy, 92: 954-964.
Heal, G. and Barrow, M. (1980) “The Relationship Between Interest Rates and Metal-
Price Movements,” Review of Economic Studies, 47: 161-182.
Hotelling, H. (1931) “The Economics of Exhaustible Resources,” Journal of Political
Huberman, G, (1987) “Arbitrage Pricing Theory,” in The New Palgrave, Finance,
Eatwell, J., Milgate. M., and Newman, P. (eds) New York: W.W. Norton.
Jovanovic, B. (1982) “Selection and the Evolution of Industry,” Econometrica, 50:
Levhari, and Levitan, (1977) “Notes on Hotelling’s Economics of Exhaustible Re-
sources,” Canadian Journal of Economics, 10: 177–192.
Lintner, J. (1965) “The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Invest-
ments in Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets,” Review of Economics and
Peltzman, S. (1977) “The Gains and Losses from Industrial Concentration,” Journalof Law and Economics, 20: 229–263.
Schmalensee, R. (1985) “Do Markets Matter Much?” American Economic Review,
Schmalensee, R. (1989) “Inter–Industry Studies of Structure and Performance,” in
Handbook of Industrial Organization, R. Schmalensee and R.D. Willig (eds.)
Scherer, F.M. and Ross, D. (1990) Industrial Market Structure and Economic Per-formance, Third Edition, Houghton Mifflin.
Scott, J.T. and Pascoe, G. (1986) “Beyond Firm and Industry Effects on Profitabil-
ity in Imperfect Markets,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 68: 284–292.
Sharpe, W.F. (1964) “Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium Under
Conditions of Risk,” Journal of Finance, 19: 425–442.
Slade, M.E. (1982) “Trends in Natural-Resource Commodity Prices: An Analysis of
the Time Domain,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 9:
Slade, M.E. and Thille, H. (1997) “Hotelling Confronts CAPM: A Test of the Theory
of Exhaustible Resources”, Canadian Journal of Economics, 30: 685–708.
Slade, M.E. (2003) “Market Power and Joint Dominance in UK Brewing,” Journalof Industrial Economics, forthcoming.
Smith, V.K. (1981) “The Empirical Relevance of Hotelling’s Model for Natural Re-
sources,” Resources and Energy, 3: 105-117.
Stigler, G.J. (1964) “A Theory of Oligopoly,” Journal of Political Economy, 72:
Stiglitz, J. (1976) “Monopoly and the Rate of Extraction of Exhaustible Resources,”
American Economic Review, 66: 655–661.
Weiss, L.W. (1974) “The Concentration Profits Relationship and Antitrust,”in In-dustrial Concentration: The New Learning, H.J. Goldschmidt and J.F. Weston
Young, D. (1992) “Cost Specification and Firm Behavior in a Hotelling Model of
Resource Extraction,” Canadian Journal of Economics,” 25: 41-59.
Table 1: Equilibrium Predictions
Table 2: Summary Statistics for Firm Variables Mining Variable Refining Variable
Profit rate in percentage. HHI is divided by 100. Size in percentage of market. Beta is multiplied by 100. Coefficient of variation = standard deviation/mean.
Table 3: Contribution of Principal Components to Variation Mining Component Refining Component
Table 4: Correlation Coefficients Refining
0.461∗∗ 0.252∗∗
* denotes significance at 5%. ** denotes significance at 1%.
EXAMPLE 1a – FRACTURE PATIENT INVITE LETTER «ClinicAddress1» «ClinicAddress2» «ClinicAddress3» «ClinicAddress4» «ClinicPostcode» «PatientTitle» «PatientFirstname» «PatientSurname» «PatientAddress1» «PatientAddress2» «PatientAddress3» «PatientAddress4» «PatientPostcode» Dear «PatientTitle» «PatientSurname» You have been referred to the os
Bradley Philip Stoner Personal Information: Sex: Citizenship: Address and Telephone Numbers: Division of Infectious Diseases Washington University School of Medicine Tel. 314-935-5673 FAX 314-935-8535 e-mail: [email protected] Present Position: Associate Professor of Anthropology Director, Medicine and Society Program Director, Undergraduate Minor in Public